02 January 2016

TTIP Update XXVI

This is probably the most action-packed update so far, and is a reflection that we are now deep in the TAFTA/TTIP negotiations.  Of course, information about what exactly is happening behind the closed doors is still thin on the ground.  To its credit, the European Commission has recently published its negotiating positions in five areas: chemicals , cosmetics , pharmaceutical products , motor vehicles , textiles and clothing.  Significantly, though, it did not publish its proposals for energy.  That's because they are far more contentious than for those other areas.  How do we know that?  Thanks to some kind person who has leaked a draft negotiating text for that area [.pdf].  Here's how the Sierra Club and PowerShift describe the Commission's moves (they also offer a fuller analysis [.pdf]:

If enacted, the proposal would:

expand fossil fuel exports from the U.S. to the EU,

increase the EU’s reliance on fossil fuel imports,

limit the ability of governments to set the terms of their energy policy, and

restrict the development of local renewable energy programs.

“This proposal exposes the contradiction of policy makers who promise to do everything they can to act on climate and then push a trade and investment agreements that would devastate our climate,” said Peter Fuchs, Executive Director of PowerShift. “Europe should phase out the use of its own fossil fuels -- and it should not be importing fracked gas or any other fossil fuel from the U.S. This proposal is more evidence as to why trade negotiators are holding the details about this deal so close to the vest.”


In part because of the lack of real transparency - for example making all the EU's tabled documents publicly available - some people last week demonstrated peacefully outside a meeting at which both Karel De Gucht, the EU commissioner responsible for TTIP, and the US Ambassador to the EU, Anthony Gardner, were speaking.  Here's what happened:

This Thursday morning over a thousand people were in the streets of Brussels, attempting to peacefully protest against austerity and the proposed great transatlantic market (TTIP) which were being discussed in the absence of citizens at the European Business Summit.

In an unprovoked move 281 people were violently arrested, including Belgian and European parliamentarians and candidates, senior trade union officials, farmers and many elderly citizens.


And this was no genteel response to a genteel demonstration: water cannons were used, and many of those arrested were cable-tied with their hands behind their back.  That's an extraordinarily disproportionate response to a peaceful demonstration, and reveals the extreme nervousness of the authorities. However, it seems likely to backfire: it was precisely this kind of attempt to tough it out that led to the fall of ACTA in 2012.

Street protests by concerned citizens may be only just beginning, but civil organisations are increasingly waking up to the dangers of TTIP and sending warning messages in ever-larger numbers.  Here's one from over 250 groups calling for greater transparency:

"The European Commission has argued that secrecy in this process is inevitable because this is a matter of international relations. However, as these negotiations are highly likely to affect domestic regulations, standards and safeguards on both sides of the Atlantic, citizens have the right to know what is being put up for negotiation, and how decisions are being made.

All negotiating documents must be made public so that a democratic debate can take place. People – not just corporations – must be able to take part in discussions about what kind of economy, environment and future we want. Continued secrecy will only fuel suspicions that the negotiations are trading away citizens' protections for the benefits of powerful industry players."


That's a key point: by its own admission, most of TTIP's possible gains will come in the regulatory sphere; regulations are about want kind of society we want to live - what the rules are.  Changing those behind closed doors is simply subverting basic democratic principles.

Another letter, again from many dozens of organisations, also concerns itself with the regulatory sphere - specifically the possibility that some kind of transatlantic regulatory council will be set up, as discussed in a previous update.  Here's the concern [.pdf]:

The top-down coordination of these measures through an institutional framework for transatlantic regulatory cooperation, we feel, would likely become a significant source of delay and preempt a state, a country, or region’s ability to maintain or establish stronger standards when consumers demand such or to respond to emerging technologies, new scientific information, preferred policies by the public, and urgent crises. One of our main concerns is that regulatory cooperation as suggested by trade negotiators will allow business groups and their lobbyists to exert undue influence in the regulatory process.

With an objective to prevent transatlantic regulatory divergence and minimize impacts to international trade, the preemptive power and influence of this institutional framework for regulatory cooperation is of particular concern.

As proposed, this body is designed to prioritize potential trade impacts over other factors in decision making. Even without a focus on trade-related impacts, cost-benefit analysis can produce unreliable results and may be heavily tilted against the public interest. Proposals to add yet more layers of analysis and governance to the rulemaking process will increase delays and will impede achieving the central mission of most regulators: to protect the public and the environment.


Of course, there's a deep irony here.  One of the declared aims of TTIP is to reduce "trade frictions", so as to boost economies on both sides of the Atlantic.  And yet, as the quoted passage above rightly points out, the regulatory council would "add yet more layers of analysis and governance to the rulemaking process will increase delays" - adding "friction".  That's simply because TTIP is about making things easier for big business, and one way of doing that is to reduce the flow of new health and safety regulations, even though the public would suffer as a result.

The proposed regulatory council is about future convergence; but another suggestion is that "non-tariff barriers" - things like health and safety rules - could be eliminated through the process of mutual recognition.  The argument here is that since no rules would be abolished, there would be no race to the bottom.  To see why that is simply not true, it's helpful to consider the specific case of chemicals:

It might come as a shock to EU voters to learn exactly how weak US laws are when it comes to toxic chemicals, especially when the US’s chief negotiator for the Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) has been claiming otherwise.  This unprecedented “trade” agreement is primarily about regulation, and threatens to create new and additional avenues for industry and government to use their influence to stall necessary action on toxic chemicals, climate change, and other critical issues that must be addressed by the EU and global community to protect human health and the environment.

How weak are US laws for toxic chemicals?  Only eleven ingredients are restricted from cosmetics in the US, versus over 1300 in the EU.  Under a law dating back to 1976, US regulators have only been able to restrict the use of merely five of over 60,000 industrial chemicals that were presumed safe when the law was adopted, including asbestos.  Under this law, and despite over a century of substantial evidence of serious adverse effects, US regulators were unable demonstrate sufficient “risk” to justify a ban on the use of asbestos, unlike EU counterparts.  Moving ahead of the US, the EU has started to implement legislation that has the potential to systematically substitute over 1000 toxic chemicals—including those linked to cancer, interference with hormone systems, reproductive harms, and other serious adverse health effects—with safer alternatives in a wide range of everyday products.  The US has no such law.


Mutual recognition of standards for cosmetics would allow some 1289 chemicals banned in Europe as toxic to be used quite legally in US-produced items.  It's easy to see that this would encourage manufacturers to move to the US where they could produce cosmetics subject to less stringent standards, and then sell them to Europe from there.

The text quoted above comes from an article on the EurActiv site, written by Baskut Tuncak, Chemicals Programme Attorney for the Center for International Environmental Law (CIEL).  That same organisation was asked by the US House subcommittee on Commerce, Manufacturing and Trade to provide answers to a variety of questions on TTIP regarding regulatory cooperation, investor-state disputes, confidential business info, and transparency.  The responses may not be for the general audience, but that offer a useful perspective on TTIP and ISDS from a US perspective.  Here, for example, is what CIEL has to say in response to a question on regulatory harmonisation and mutual recognition [.pdf]:

Whether regulatory harmonization or the mutual recognition of standards would diminish the regulatory sovereignty of the United States and the European Union, i.e., constrain the ability of the two entities to promulgate regulations it deems uniquely appropriate for the specific threats to the health and safety of their respective citizens.

Yes, regulatory harmonization or the mutual recognition of standards would diminish the regulatory sovereignty of both the United States and the European Union, both at the highest levels of government and, critically, at the subnational and subregional levels where regulatory innovations most often originate. Negotiators have stated that TTIP would not affect the right of the U.S. and the EU to regulate; however, TTIP would affect the ability of these Parties, including states and Member States, to exercise this right.

The proposed institutional framework for regulatory cooperation would be composed of representatives from both Parties, and cover “any planned and existing regulatory measures of general application” and “extend to regulations by US States and EU Member States.” It would have the unstated power to constrain the ability of the either Party to exercise its right to promulgate regulations it deems uniquely appropriate for the specific threats to the health and safety of their respective citizens. Some of the key elements of this implicit power include:

The use of “harmonization, recognition of equivalence, or mutual recognition” as tools for regulatory "cooperation"...;

The use of “cost-benefit” and “trade impact” analyses for proposed regulatory or legislative initiatives, with a special focus on international trade impacts, to be published with the proposed final measure;

A requirement for “regulatory dialogues,” with trans-Atlantic governments;

The creation of a trans-Atlantic scientific body to guide regulatory decision making ; and

The right of “stakeholders” to table “substantive joint submissions” for this body to consider.

These types of provisions are designed to weaken or delay the development and implementation laws that specifically address priorities of either U.S. or EU citizens that might not be reflected across the Atlantic. For example, the recent decision to abandon the EU’s Fuel Quality Directive, which sought to curb the use of dirty energy sources and encourage renewable, was abandoned due to U.S. government and industry interference over the potential trade-related impacts. An institutional framework would create a permanent avenue for foreign interference with the development and implementation of laws and policies sought by the public in the U.S. or EU to reflect their own values, judgments, circumstances and policy choices.


Although not exactly light reading, it's an impressive document with links to many useful sources.   It's a sign of the increasingly detailed and sophisticated response that organisations like CIEL are putting together as they gird their loins in the by-now intense battle over TTIP.

Full list of previous TTIP Updates.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XXV

On Monday, a couple of things happened in the world of TTIP - both, as it happens, in Berlin.  More importantly, the main TTIP circus flew into town: that means not just Karel De Gucht, the European Commissioner with responsibility on the European side, but also Michael Froman, the US Trade Representative (USTR), and thus the leader of the US negotiations.  The occasion was "The Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership Dialogue Forum", hosted by the German Finance Minister, Sigmar Gabriel, who also spoke alongside the two negotiators.

Gabriel was the most interesting speaker, not least because he was originally sceptical about TTIP - until he became Germany's Finance Minister, when he was presumably told to toe the government line.  In particular, what was really striking about his speech was his constant call for transparency: indeed, he went so far as to say that negotiatoins without transparency are simply not acceptable in a democracy.  That sounds great, but I doubt it will have much effect. When Froman was asked about providing more transparency, he basically said "no", without offering any credible justification for that stance.  Even De Gucht seemed to want more transparency, which shows that it is only the US side that is blocking things.

Overall, the event was pretty tedious.  Nothing dramatically new was said, and all the tired old platitudes - and FUD -  were trotted out.  What was most significant was that it took place at all.  As was admitted at the beginning of the event, the reason for the unprecedented wheeling out of the political heavyweights is that TTIP is in big trouble, and nowhere more so than Germany.  Just as Germany led the successful revolt against ACTA, so it is in the vanguard of resistance to TTIP.  The hope - albeit a rather desperate one - was that bringing on the main players, the German public would suddenly be won over.  I don't think so, somehow., and one of the indications that the politicians are wasting their time is that a petition against TTIP, organised by the German organisation Campact, has already garnered over 470,000 signatures at the time of writing.

This fact led to a very telling exchange at the conference.  De Gucht said to Campact's Maritta Strasser that *she* might have 500,000 signatures, but *he* represented 500 million Europeans, and that she had a long way to go before she could match his legitimacy.  Of course, it seems to have slipped his mind that nobody actually voted for him: he was just given his post as part of the weird European Union apportionment of power.   The idea that he "represents" the 500 million people who pay his salary, let alone that this legitimises his secret discussions on TTIP shows how contemptuous he is of ordinary citizens who want to follow what is going on and to give their input.

It explains precisely why the German people, among others, are so sceptical about the value of TTIP to them and their families, and is the primary reason why De Gucht and Froman had to be flown in to perform this desperate bit of firefighting to "save" the agreement before it is too late.  It also explains why that propaganda stunt failed completely: because the politicians pushing TTIP simply do not understand - or probably even care - what ordinary people think about the negotiations.

The other thing that happened in Berlin on Monday to do with TTIP - rather less important - was that I gave a talk on the subject at re:publica 14, arguably the best tech conference around at the moment.  I've embedded the talk here:



and my slides below.



Readers of this column won't find anything particularly new, but the presentation has the virtue of being relatively short (only about 20 minutes), and thus I hope it could be quite useful as an introduction for people who don't know much or anything about this important agreement.  It's followed by a longer panel discussion where various aspects are explored, including questions from the audience.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XXIV

In an early update, I wrote about the leak of the European Commission's communication strategy for "overcoming public scepticism" about TAFTA/TTIP.  The key section was probably the following:

Making sure that the broad public in each of the EU Member States has a general understanding of what TTIP is (i.e. an initiative that aims at delivering growth and jobs) and what it is not (i.e. an effort to undermine regulation and existing levels of protection in areas like health, safety and the environment).

That clearly hasn't succeeded - we've seen increasing discussion and concern about how there could be a regulatory race to the bottom, and about the elevation of corporations to the same level as nations through the unbridled power of the investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) mechanism.  The failure to control the narrative about the latter has led to the European Commission's consultation on ISDS - although, as I noted in my previous update, that's largely a PR exercise, and won't make any substantive difference to what the Commission and its negotiators will do.

However, in one respect, the Commission's communication strategy is going according to plan: the vast majority of reporting on TTIP accepts at face value not just the figures that are being bandied around for the supposed gains from TTIP, but the larger underlying assumption that there will in fact be gains at all.  Part of the problem is that there is strikingly little research into the benefits and costs of TTIP.  That's truly extraordinary: no one would think of setting up a business without investigating both exhaustively, by trying to forecast the outcome of various alternatives.  And yet the European Commission wants us to buy into the largest global trade agreement ever attempted with far less research or justification than most of us would need before even buying a second-hand car.

It is doing that by rolling out the same numbers every time it talks about the claimed benefits: those found in research which it paid for, from the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR).  I've talked about these in earlier updates, and discussed why they are not at all what they seem - and certainly not the massive gains the European Commission keeps talking about.  But my view hardly carriers much weight against the economists that put it together.  What we need is another qualified team to look critically at the assumptions and results.  Fortunately for us, the Confederal Group of the European United Left/Nordic Green Left (GUE/NGL) has commissioned a group of researchers to do precisely that.

Now, it might be claimed that its report, "Assessing the Claimed Benefits of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership" [.pdf] inevitably brings with it an agenda.  But exactly the same is true of the research carried out on behalf of the Commission.  What's important is that we have a range of views on the economic impact of TTIP, and that we don't just assume one study is the last word on the matter - which is essentially where we are today.  What makes the new study, which has been put together by the Austrian Foundation for Development Research, particularly valuable is that it does not restrict itself to the main CEPR work, but looks at all the available studies, of which there are now four - still a frighteningly small number given what is at stake.  Here's the basic result:

All of the four scrutinized studies report small, but positive effects on GDP, trade flows and real wages in the EU. GDP and real wage increases are however estimated by most studies to range from 0.3 to 1.3 %, even in the most optimistic liberalization scenarios. These changes refer to a level change within 10 to 20 years (!), annual GDP growth during this transition period would thus amount to 0.03 to 0.13 % at most.

This confirms what I wrote in Update XXI: the possible benefits are really very small.  What's important to note here is that that this emerges from four separate analyses.  However, the new study GUE/NGL mentions another crucially important effect of TTIP - one that I've rather underestimated:

According to three studies, TTIP benefits will however come at the cost of reducing bilateral trade between EU Member States. In a deep liberalization scenario, intra-EU trade could fall by around 30 %. The reason for this is that these EU countries’ exports will be substituted for by cheaper Extra-EU imports.

This makes sense: as the barriers to selling in the US drop, so more EU trade will take place with it.  However, one of the collateral effects will be that EU countries sell less to each other, since they can presumably make more money sending their goods overseas.  This leads to a paradoxical effect:  a treaty that is partly being sold on the basis that it will strengthen the EU, will actually hollow it out, as intra-EU trade diminishes.  That means people who support TTIP because they believe it will re-inforce Europe will need to think again: TTIP might actually be the final blow that leads to the disintegration of the European Union, turning it into a looser economic grouping.

That's one important fact to emerge from this analysis; arguably even more important is the new work the Austrian team have carried out to address what is perhaps the biggest flaw in the European Commission's argument that TTIP will bring huge benefits - the fact that the corresponding costs are not calculated to allow an overall balance to be drawn.  Again, it is extraordinary that the Commission is asking people to support TAFTA without revealing the costs that are likely to be involved.  Here's one important category of them:

Adjustment costs are mostly neglected or downplayed in the TTIP studies. This refers in particular to macroeconomic adjustment costs, which can come in the form of (i) changes to the current account balance, (ii) losses to public revenues, and (iii) changes to the level of unemployment.

The first of these is unlikely to be major, but the other two could well be. After all, if tariff barriers are eliminated, there is bound to be some loss of government revenue:

We would thus estimate cumulated income losses to be in the order of €20 billion over a period of 10 years, also depending on tariff exemptions and phase-in periods for sensitive goods.

Three of the studies assume that there will be no permanent unemployment as a result of TTIP (quite a big assumption, given the current economic situation), while one predicts unemployment will be reduced.  But even in that case, there is likely to be worker displacement, as the effects of TTIP are felt differently in different industries.  This will lead to temporary unemployment, retraining, and probably downgrading of jobs.  All of these impose costs on the economy:

A rough calculation yields annual expenses for unemployment benefits of between €0.5 – €1.4 billion during a TTIP implementation period of 10 years. Thus a cumulative €5 – €14 billion might be necessary to finance a part of the adjustment costs on the labor market, with additional costs for re-training and skills-acquisition not included in this amount. To this amount, a further loss of public revenue from foregone tax income and social security contributions between €4 - €10 billion has to be added.

The final category of costs is perhaps the most important, because it exposes another massive assumption in the European Commission's figures:

Another type of costs ignored refers to the regulatory change resulting from TTIP. All studies, but particularly the Ecorys study, assume that a reduction of NTMs [non-tariff measures] is welfare-enhancing. This ignores that NTM such as laws, regulations and standards pursue public policy goals. They correct for market failures or safeguard collective preferences of a society. As such they are themselves welfare-enhancing. The elimination or alignment of an NTM thus will imply a social cost for society. This applies equally to NTM elimination, harmonization and mutual recognition.

This is something else I had not appreciated.  The removal of "non-tariff barriers/measures" is one of the most contentious areas of TTIP since those "barriers" are things like health and safety regulations.  The fact that their removal is being treated as "welfare-enhancing" - improving the lot of society - is a truly outrageous redefinition of both society and welfare.  It might well boost the bottom lines of companies that pollute the environment, say, but that can hardly been called "welfare enhancing".  Thus what are currently being counted as *benefits* are probably actually costs, as the Austrian economists go on to point out:

the elimination of NTMs will result in a potential welfare loss to society, in so far as this elimination threatens public policy goals (e.g. consumer safety, public health, environmental safety), which are not taken care of by some other measure or policy. The analysis of NTMs in the Ecorys study completely ignores these problems. Instead, it is assumed that around 50 % or 25% of all existing NTMs between the EU und the US are actionable, i.e. can be eliminated or aligned to some international standard, while CEPR assumes a 25% actionability level. This includes sensitive sectors such as foods & beverages, chemicals, pharmaceuticals and cosmetics or automotives. In order to arrive at its optimistic welfare estimations, strong reductions/alignments of NTMs in precisely those sectors are necessary, where the safeguarding of public policy goals is perhaps most crucial. It is highly doubtful that such high levels of actionability could be implemented without any losses to the quality of regulation in the public interest. Though subject to considerable uncertainty, the incurred social costs of TTIP regulatory change might be substantial, and require careful case-by-case analysis.

That's putting it mildly.

As I hope you can see, this is a really important contribution to the TTIP debate, since it not only examines existing studies, and subjects them to an extremely detailed analysis running to dozens of pages, but it also raises crucial issues that have so far been almost completely ignored.  Key among those are the costs of TTIP - which turn out to include aspects that somehow have been magically transformed into benefits, simply by ignoring their true impact on the public.

That's just one among many reasons to take a look at this work.  Although the technical critique of the impact assessment studies are hard going unless you are an economist, the report's authors have very thoughtfully provided not just one, but two summaries: a condensed one, and an extended version.  These do not require any technical econometric knowledge and should be read by anyone who wants to form a more balanced view on what the real benefits and costs of TTIP are likely to be.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XXIII

In my last update, I noted that the problems with investor-state dispuate settlement (ISDS) are multiplying, as lawyers latch on to the fact that it is an extremely efficient way of extracting large sums of money for very little cost (for example, I mentioned one case where an investment of $5 million led to an award of $900 million for "lost profits".)  In fact, things are so bad even the European Commission has noticed.

That's partly because of the enormous pushback from people once they twigged what ISDS entails.  Until a few months ago, this was an extremely obscure aspect of an inherently dry and dull area, so it's no wonder that few people knew or cared about it.  But once they realised that it would have immense impact on their lives - both directly in terms of the huge pay-outs that *they* would have to fund through taxes, and indirectly in terms of the chilling effect on future legislation and regulation people started to make their concerns known.

The most dramatic manifestation of that upswell of outrage is that the European Commission unexpectedly announced that it would be holding a "consultation" on ISDS.  That was doubly significant.  It showed that the Commission was sensitive to public outcry, and it also created a precedent: if a consultation could be held on ISDS, why not on all the other aspects of TTIP?

However, a big question mark hung over the consultation - for example, some have seen it as a cynical ploy to remove ISDS from public discourse until *after* the imminent elections for the European Parliament, so that they are not an important theme there.  There is now a home page for the consultation and its associated documents, and it's well-worth examining them in order to gain insights into the Commission's thinking on this score.

The "Consultation notice" [.pdf] contains some interesting background:

Given the strong public interest in this issue the European Commission is consulting the public in the EU on a possible approach to investment protection and ISDS that contains a series of innovative elements outlined below and that the EU intends to use as the basis for t he TTIP negotiations. The key issue on which we are consulting is whether the EU’s proposed approach for TTIP achieves the right balance between protectin g investors and safeguarding the EU 's right and ability to regulate in the public interest .

That attempt to create a false "balance" between "protecting investors" and "safeguarding the EU 's right and ability to regulate in the public interest" is perhaps the clearest indication of why we do not need ISDS.  There should be no question of trading away the right to regulate in return for investor protection: they belong to entirely different policy universes.  Their complete independence is demonstrated clearly by some statistics on the European Commission's own site.  I make no apology for wheeling them out yet again because they drive a stake through the heart of the Commission's argument for ISDS:

Total US investment in the EU is three times higher than in all of Asia.

EU investment in the US is around eight times the amount of EU investment in India and China together.

EU and US investments are the real driver of the transatlantic relationship, contributing to growth and jobs on both sides of the Atlantic. It is estimated that a third of the trade across the Atlantic actually consists of intra-company transfers.


There is no need to trade off sovereignty for "investor protection", because people are already investing both ways across the Atlantic on a scale that is unmatched in the rest of the world. There is simply no problem that needs solving, and so ISDS is just unnecessary.

The rest of the Consultation notice tries to ignore this key fact by quoting a bunch of irrelevant statistics:

So far, the EU 's Member States have concluded about 1400 Bilateral Investment Treaties on the protection of investment. Virtually all such agreements include ISDS. While nine EU Member States currently have bilateral investment treaties with the US, other s do not. This situation means
that some EU investors in the US are treated differently co mpared to other EU investors, and that US investors have more rights in some EU Member States than in others .


As I've noted before, those 1400 bilateral treaties were essentially the EU imposing onerous conditions on developing countries; ISDS was there to be used as an offensive weapon.  Including it in TTIP will simply hand 50,800 US subsidiaries the most powerful legal weapon they could possibly wish for.

And as for the nine EU Member States that already have bilateral treaties with the US, what this fails to mention is who exactly those are: Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania and the Slovak Republic.  In other words, these were all countries that had been forced into the Soviet sphere, and which were therefore desperate to strengthen links with the US when the Soviet Union collapsed.  Dwarfed by the latter's economy, there were in no position to haggle, and naturally accepted ISDS as part of the deal.

Unless the European Commission wants to suggest that the other 19 members of the EU should be equally supine in agreeing to whatever the US demands, those earlier bilateral treaties born of real fears over economic and military security, are completely irrelevant to TTIP, and offer no precedent for including ISDS.

The other important element of the Consultation notice is the claim that whatever problems ISDS might have had in the past, the Commission is *on* it:

The Commission is propos ing a n innovative approach on investment protection and ISDS for the TT I P. It draws on lessons learnt and from experience with existing inve s t ment treaties and with how the ex isting ISDS arbitration system works . It addresses the concerns and shortcomings that have featured prominently in public discussion s a bout investment protection and ISDS .

Sounds great, but there's a problem: Karel De Gucht has not kept his promise as regards letting us see exactly how the Commission proposes to address ISDS's admitted "concerns and shortcomings".  Here's what he said when he announced it:

In early March, he will publish a proposed EU text for the investment part of the talks which will include sections on investment protection and on investor-to-state dispute settlement, or ISDS. This draft text will be accompanied by clear explanations for the non-expert. People across the EU will then have three months to comment.

The problem is that there is still no draft text of the ISDS chapter for us to examine.  Instead, this is what we've got in the main consultation document [.pdf]:

Each issue is illustrated using reference texts as examples , taken from other investment agreements and from the approach developed in the EU - Canada (CET A) negotiations, which is the most recent text negotiated by the EU.

That is, instead of that promised "draft text", we have "examples", and a recent text of the provisions in the Canada-EU Trade Agreement (CETA) that has been discussed several times in these updates, of which Update XIV is probably the most relevant here.  That's because it reports on some great analysis carried out by the Seattle to Brussels Network (SBN), working from a late, leaked copy of CETA's ISDS provisions.  This shows that essentially all of the claimed "improvements" that the Commission has made to ISDS in CETA are actually pretty worthless: they are full of loopholes and loose wording that skilled lawyers will have a field day with.

That means there are only two possible situations.  Either the Commission proposes to use a text close to that employed in CETA - in which case, the ISDS provisions are just as dangerous as they have always been, and the cosmetic changes made by the Commission will do little to change that.  Or else the Commission plans to use a radically different text from the one in CETA that does address the serious problems - in which case the current consultation is pointless, since we can't actually see that text, despite what De Gucht said.

Either way, the ISDS consultation is a sham, and should not be regarded as a serious attempt to engage with "the public", despite fervid claims to the contrary.  In a future Update I'll be making specific recommendations about how to reply to it before the closing date of 6 July 2014.  As you can probably guess, the tenor of my response will be simple: we don't need ISDS in TTIP, so don't even bother trying to salvage it - just get rid of it completely.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XXII

The fact that corporations are regularly placed on the same level as entire nations, and can sue them for alleged loss of future profits, probably came as something of a shock to most people, as it did to me when I first encountered the idea.  It sounded like the deranged fantasy of some corporate lobbyist, but surely not something that any country would actually accept.  And yet, as we know, not only do many - small, and relatively weak - countries consent to investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) as the price of obtaining much-needed inward investment, but the European Commission seems hell-bent on exposing European to the same kind of corporate attack.

I say "Europeans", and not European nations, because ultimately it is the taxpayers that must fund the increasingly exorbitant awards that ISDS tribunals are making.  To put it another way, it's a classic case of "privatising the profit, and socialising the costs": EU companies get to make profits in the US, but it's mostly the EU citizens who would have to foot the bill if awards were made under ISDS in favour of American corporations operating here in Europe.

Even though ISDS burst upon the scene relatively recently for most of us, we actually have a fair amount of information about its previous history, largely thanks to bodies like the United Nations Conference on Trade And Development (UNCTAD), which has been producing handy summaries of what's been happening in this strange world for a while now.  It's just published its latest report [.pdf], and it contains some important developments. The number of new cases is only one less than the previous year's record - 57 against 58.  More significant is the following:

The greatest number of 2013 cases were brought against countries in Europe (26 cases, of which two are against countries not members of the European Union (EU) – Albania and Serbia)

Specifically:

Twenty four arbitrations (42 per cent of all cases) were brought against EU Member States. The range of countries involved is broad and includes “new” and “old” Member States, namely the Czech Republic (7 cases), Spain (6), Croatia (2), Hungary (2), Slovakia (2), Bulgaria (1), Cyprus (1), France (1), Greece (1), and Slovenia (1). In all of these arbitrations except for one, the claimants are also EU nationals; they started the proceedings on the basis of either intra-EU bilateral investment treaties (BITs) or the Energy Charter Treaty (ECT), sometimes relying on both at the same time.

That's an important shift, since it shows that ISDS is no longer simply a way for Western countries to bully developing ones, but that the weapon has now been turned against many EU countries, mostly by other EU countries.  This suggests that companies are becoming aware of and more comfortable with ISDS as a way of extracting money from EU governments.  Couple that with the fact that overall the US is the leading nation when it comes to using ISDS - 127 cases out of 568 (22%) -  and that there are  more than 14,400 US-based corporations that own more than 50,800 subsidiaries in the EU, and you have a recipe for an ISDS-based legal Armageddon.

The report contains some other significant straws in the wind:

Several arbitrations launched in 2013 have an environmental dimension. In two disputes against Canada, investors are challenging measures introduced on environmental grounds. The first, a claim by Lone Pine Resources, arose out of Quebec’s moratorium on hydraulic fracturing (fracking) that led to the revocation of the company’s gas exploration permits. The second dispute relates to Ontario’s moratorium on offshore wind farms (pending research on their health and environmental effects); the claimant contends that the temporary ban breaches its contract for the electricity supply which it had concluded with the Ontario Power Authority for a 20-year period.

This is precisely the kind of things that many fear will happen if ISDS is included in TTIP: companies will seek to overturn policies that are brought in for environmental reasons, arguing that corporate profits outweigh the rights of the public.  The following case is also highly relevant to the EU situation:

Achmea, a Dutch insurance company, is seeking to preclude the host State from expropriating Achmea’s stake in a Slovak health insurer (the relevant draft law is under consideration by the Slovak Parliament). The right of States to expropriate property is well-established under international investment law as long as certain conditions are met. Achmea is claiming that some of these conditions would be breached (requirement of public interest, non- discrimination and due process) if the expropriation goes ahead.

A similar situation could arise in the UK if a future government decided to reverse the current privatisation of NHS services, and sought to re-nationalise them.  If a US company were involved, it might claim that the UK could not expropriate property in this way because conditions to do so were not met.

The UNCTAD report is really well-worth reading in order to gain an understanding of how ISDS is developing - and how quickly.  For example, there are cases where companies try to claim "moral damages" along with everything else, and another case where a company that had made a $5 million investment was awarded $900 million in "lost profits" - even though it seems to have no track record as a profitable organisation.

Trade lawyers around the world have clearly realised that ISDS is one of the most efficient ways for their clients to extract money from governments, and they are applying their not-inconsiderable - if largely amoral - ingenuity to come up with new ways of using the mechanism.  That's another important reason why the "innovative elements" the European Commission plans to introduce to "improve" the system won't work - they are trying to fix yesterday's problems - and why ISDS must be removed completely from TTIP.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+


TTIP Update XXI


In Update XX, I noted that despite the European Commission's claims to the contrary, there was simply no evidence of any meaningful transparency in TTIP.  However, that changed today, when the Commission announced its consultation on investor-state dispute settlement.  That's because as well as the questions and useful background explanations, the consultation document [.pdf] includes not only provisions found in typical bilateral investment treaties but - and this is particularly welcome - the relevant text developed in the Canada-EU trade agreement (CETA).  That is what transparency looks like, and needs to be extended to all the other chapters.

However, I don't intend to go through the consultation document here: I'll save that for another update (we have three months to reply to the consultation, so there's no huge rush.)  Instead, I want to address an issue that comes up again and again, and which represents such a serious misrepresentation of the facts, that I really want to try to deal with it once and for all.

It concerns the famous 119 billion euros figure for the "extra" GDP growth that TTIP will produce, which I've mentioned several times before.  Here's its latest appearance, on a page from the powerful EPP political group in the European Parliament, which is entitled "Mythbusting the EU-US free trade agreement".  The relevant section reads as follows:

What's in it for the EU?

The impact assessment launched by the European Union before the start of negotiations in March 2013 suggested that the EU's economy could benefit by 119 billion euros a year and the US economy could gain an extra 95 billion a year - with gains of 545 euros for each EU family. These gains would be the result of removing tariffs and doing away with unnecessary rules and bureaucratic hurdles that make it difficult to buy and sell across the Atlantic.


Notice there's that "119 billion euros" figure, but notice that the claim is Europe would gain this *each year*.  The @EPPGroup account confirmed to me that the EPP had obtained that number from the main European Commission research on the economic impact on TTIP, "Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment ; An Economic Assessment" [.pdf].  And sure enough, on page vii of that document, in the Key Findings section, we read:

An ambitious and comprehensive transatlantic trade and iinvestment agreement could bring significant economic gains as a whole for the EU (€119 billion a year) and US (€95 billion a year). 

This translates to an extra €545 in disposable income each year for a family of 4 in the EU, on average, and €655 per family in the US.


This is very curious, because that's not what the actual report says at all. 

The correct interpretation is found on page 3 of the report, where we find that 119 billion euros figure again, which is explained as the change in GDP.  But it is not the change in GDP *each year*, which is what the Key Findings section claims; in rather small print on that page, underneath the table labelled "Summary of Macroeconomic Effect", we read the words:

Note:  estimates to be interpreted as changes relative to a projected 2027 global economy

The fact that the Key Findings is wrong is confirmed on page 33 of the report, which explains things at more length:

The results are reported with respect to an economic benchmark projected out to the year 2027 which implies that that they capture the impact of the agreement a full ten years after the implementation of the agreement, providing the longer-term impact of policy changes.

As that makes clear, the results give the difference between two situations: the EU's economy in 2027 if TTIP had been in place for ten years, and the EU's economy in 2027 without TTIP.  The different is expressed as the extra GDP that would result - 119 billion euros in the most optimistic case.

So what the report is saying is that the extra growth that TTIP could bring in 2027 relative to the economy in 2027 without TTIP in 119 billion euros. 
Which means that the 119 billion euros is the *cumulative* benefit for those ten years of TTIP, compared to the ten years without TTIP.  On average, then, the claim is that TTIP could produce 11.9 billion euros extra for the European economy each year, for ten years, giving an *overall* boost to the EU GDP of 119 billion.Which means that the 119 billion euros is the *eventual* level of GDP boost, after 10 years.

It can be a little hard juggling abstractions like extra growth in GDP over a decade; so let's look at the other figure that the Key Findings mentions: "an extra €545 in disposable income each year for a family of 4 in the EU," which works out as around 136 euros per person. Assuming there are 500 million people in the EU, if that figure were *each year*, as claimed, this would give a total increase in EU disposable income of 500 million times 136 euros, which equals 68 billion euros, each year, thanks to TTIP.

But as we've seen, the increase in GDP each year is only around 12 billion euros on average.  So that 68 billion euros figure clearly refers to the *cumulative* increase in disposable income in 2027, after 10 years of TTIP, compared to what what people would have had in 2027 without TTIP, just as the figure of 119 billion euros refers to the cumulative gain for the economy.

Put another way, that 545 euros is the *total* increase in disposable income across 10 years, not the extra disposable income available each year, as the Key Findings erroneously claims.  That equates to an average of 60 euros extra, per year, for a family of 4.


In other words, even under the most optimistic assumptions, and using the European Commission's own forecasts, the real-life effect of TTIP would be that each week, everyone in a typical European family of 4 would be able to buy an extra cup of coffee, but only after TTIP had been in place for 10 years.  Before that people will have to share their coffee.

As this shows, even under the most favourable assumptions - assumptions that are unlikely to be realised - TTIP's benefit to European citizens would be negligible.  The threats, on the other hand, are considerable, not least from investor-state dispute settlement, which is likely to cast a chill over legislative initiatives in the European Union, just as it did in Canada under NAFTA.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XX

At this stage of the negotiations it's clear that there are two controversial areas: investor-state dispute settlement, and transparency.  I've discussed ISDS extensively in the previous updates, so here I'd like to look more closely at transparency - or rather its absence.

As I mentioned in my previous update, the fact that that US Trade Representative felt compelled to release a document that it called "U.S. Objectives, U.S. Benefits In the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership: A Detailed View" is a sign that it knows full well that the talks so far have been almost totally devoid of transparency: the document is a sop - nothing more - to the crescendo of voices calling for real openness.  After all, had transparency been something that the USTR truly cared about, it would have released the document as soon as the TTIP negotiations began, not some arbitrary number of months later.

Further proof that the US and European Commission are under pressure is a new document from the latter entitled "Towards an EU-US trade deal: Making trade work for you" with the subhead "We're listening and engaging" [.pdf].  And if you were wondering who "you" is, here's a clue:

We know we'll only get the best deal - one that benefits as many Europeans as possible - if we involve everyone with a stake in the outcome, at every stage.  That's why we're consulting the public.

The rest of the four-page document is essentially geared to trying to demonstrate that fact.  Here, for example:

1. Consulting and updating the public

We're using the web to get a clearer idea of the wider public's wishes and concerns."


Great. So how might the European Commission be doing that?

Before the talks started we held three online consultations to better understand the measures people want us to take to boost EU-US trade and investment.

Well, that's impressive, no?  Just one small problem. Even though I follow trade deals pretty closely - indeed, I sometime think I'm the only person reading some of these documents apart from those drafting them and their mothers - I didn't take part in any of those consultations.  Not, as you might imagine, because I didn't think they were important, or that I wanted to keep my views secret, but for the simple reason that I never heard about them.  Any of them.  And I would humbly like to submit that if I didn't get to hear about them, not many members of the public did either (indeed, I'd really like to hear from any readers that did know about any of these three consultations.) 

I've now managed to track down some of those consultations.  For example, according to the results of one held in 2012, a total of 114 submissions were made, of which precisely 8 came from citizens. Another consultation from earlier that year received 48 submissions, of which two look as if they might be from the public.  That's transparency?

Of course, for the next TTIP consultation, things are likely to be very different, because we all know it's coming, and are keen to take part:

A fourth consultation asks for the public's views on our draft ideas on protect ing investors . These include improvements to a system known as investor - state dispute settlement, or ISDS, which dates back over 30 years.

There are (at least) three interesting things about that short statement.  First, the complete non-sequitur that ISDS dates back over 30 years.  As I've discussed at length, the point is that ISDS has never existed between the US and European Union, and yet despite that fact, the US has invested 1.3 trillion euros in Europe, and Europe 1.4 trillion euros in the US, so the absence of ISDS doesn't seem to have deterred investors that much.

The second point is that the consultation will be about "protecting investors" - not, as you might hope, about protecting the public, who are the main ones threatened by the ability of corporations to sue entire nations under ISDS, with the taxpayer footing the billing when the companies win.  No, we're only being asked about how to protect those defenceless international investors.

Finally, we have flagged up here the fact that the public will be asked for comments to "improvements" the system, which suggests that we will not be given the option to reject the idea completely.  Instead, I suspect, the questions will be framed largely in terms of "do you think the improvements are, er, improvements."  We shall see - this consultation is rumoured to be coming out later this week.

This section on "Consulting and updating the public" concludes:

We also post regular updates on our dedicated webpages and on Twitter . And we regularly brief the press.

That's good, but is purely about "updating the public": the striking thing is that the only "consulting" going on in this section was from those mysteriously invisible three consultations that very few members of the public responded to.  So as evidence of "transparency" I think we can call this section a failure.

Other sections try to convince us that talking to the governments of the 28 member states, to MEPs, and to some "TTIP Advisory Group" somehow counts as transparency, but of course it doesn't.  It keeps the information in the same restricted circles it's always been in (and even then, we know that very little useful information is passed on to MEPs, say.)  Section 4 "Hearing from other interest groups" - recognises there are others involved:

We want to hear from everyone with a stake in this agreement.

We regularly meet people from firms large and small, and from industry bodies.  This is, after all, a deal about the mechanics of doing business.  So we need their input.


That's absolutely true - and nobody said they shouldn't provide it.  But the other side of the coin is that this is a deal about the everyday lives of 500 million Europeans, and so we need *their* input.  Here's how the Commission thinks it is getting it:

But we also listen to people from:

consumer associations
trades unions
environmental groups and other NGOs


In addition:

Since 2012, we've held seven meetings in Brussels - each time with hundreds of people.

Well, yes, but unfortunately it tends to be hundreds of people from companies.  For example, back in January, the European Commission organised what it called an "Outreach" session in Brussels.  It sounded promising:

As part of an ongoing commitment to transparency, DG TRADE is organising a second Civil Society Dialogue to discuss progress and to exchange views on the TTIP.

Well, that's great - except for one tiny detail: out of the 196 entities registered as taking part, only about 30 were from civil society: the rest were - you guessed it - from companies and their lobbying organisations.  In other words, wherever you turn, it is always business that has the loudest voice, and has most of the Commission's attention.  Civil society - never mind the actual public - barely gets a look in.

The final hope for some transparency is the sharing of documents, covered in section 5 of the new text:

We aim to share as many documents as possible - not just with governments and MEPs, but also with out panel and the public.

Hooray - the public gets a mention. 

In fact we've published more than 50 documents online, including:

factsheets and FAQs
press releases and memos
studies and meeting reports


Well, I'm sorry, you can't claim things like factsheets, FAQs and press releases as examples of transparency: they are created purely for the purpose of being distributed.  What we want are the key documents that are being used for the negotiations.

In any negotiation, partners need to build trust.  For that they need a degree of confidentiality. 

So there are some text we can only show to governments and MEPs - like our offers to the US to:

cut tariffs on goods they export to us open our services markets to their firms.


While it is true those details need to be kept secret before the negotiations, once thay have been laid on the negotiating table for the US to see and discuss, they are no longer secret by definition, and thus can be published, since they would reveal nothing to the US that is not already known.  So by the European Commission's own arguments, tabled documents could be made available to the public in whose name they are being negotiated.

As the above makes plain, the Commission's claims for transparency are pretty weak.  That's evident from its parting shot:

But at the end of the process, the whole deal will be open to scrutiny in any case.

And the final decision comes with a double democratic guarantee.  Only a majority of both EU governments and MEPs can approve an agreement.


This is just an insult to our intelligence.  There is no meaningful "scrutiny" at the end of the process, because nothing - zero - can be changed at this point.  Instead, it's a "take it or leave it" decision that will be offered to the European Parliament.  And we know exactly how the conversation will go: "yes, there may be things you absolutely hate in there, but you've *got* to accept it otherwise you will be personally responsible for throwing away all those jobs..." - moral blackmail in other words.   Of course, as I've shown elsewhere, that's not even true - the European Commission's own figures show that the extra annual GDP that TTIP would produce in the most optimistic case is just 0.05% - statistically indistinguishable from zero. 

But the European Commission won't let a little thing like facts get in the way; which is precisely why it refuses to allow any real transparency for TTIP.  That would show all-too clearly that is the transnational corporations that benefit, and that the majority of their gains - 80% according to the Commission's own predictions - come from cost-cutting made possible by deregulation through the elimination of "non-tariff barriers" - health and safety standards, environmental regulation and the like.  And no amount of re-assuring four-page documents with key words printed in bold for easy consumption will change that.

Full list of previous TTIP Updates.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XIX

In my last update I raised the issue of an apparently obscure facet of investment chapters - the presence of "Most Favoured Nation" clauses - that actually undermined any attempts to bring in "safeguards" against the manifest dangers of that form of supranational corporate sovereignty known as investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS).  Cynics among you probably thought this was nit-picking, but support for the idea has arrived from a rather surprising quarter:

According to Rupert Schlegelmilch, director of services, investment and procurement at DG Trade, speaking on behalf of the Commission at a public debate yesterday on investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) and the TTIP, the EU is rethinking a “Most Favoured Nation” (MFN) article in the CETA investment chapter that new analysis suggests undermines much of the more careful language in the treaty relating to a government's ability to regulate. As written, the MFN article would let Canadian and EU investors ignore the definitions of “fair and equitable treatment” or “indirect expropriation” in CETA and take other more investor-friendly language from past agreements signed by either party.

Obviously, it's great news that the European Commission has recognised there's a problem here, and is trying to do something about it.  But this incident actually underlines a much bigger point.  The problem with MFN only emerged because the CETA chapter dealing with ISDS was leaked.  That meant that experts such as Nathalie Bernasconi-Osterwalder and Howard Mann at the International Institute for Sustainable Development were able to spot this huge loophole there [.pdf].  But that immediately raises the question: how many other serious problems are lurking in the many other chapters of CETA for which we do not have leaked versions? Would it not be better to have many experts searching for loopholes in the agreement *before* it is signed, rather than afterwards, when fixing them will be very hard, if not impossible?

Really, this comes down to applying Linus' Law -  the insight that given enough eyeballs, all bugs are shallow - to the code of international treaties.  Not to do so is wilfully to throw away the power of parallelised production, which allows better results to be produced much more quickly.  In other words, keeping texts secret is not just an insult to the public in whose name they are being negotiated, but actually leads to worse results thanks to the lack of proper scrutiny.

So, in the absence of texts that have been discussed during the latest round of the TAFTA/TTIP negotations - texts that are by definition not secret, since they have been discussed by both sides - in this update I will analyse some other documents that provide useful insights.

For example, the US Trade Representative, which is the negotiation partner for the European Commission, has released what it calls "U.S. Objectives, U.S. Benefits In the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership: A Detailed View".  That in itself is interesting, and shows that it is feeling the pressure to open up.  Of course, releasing one very general document does little to address that, but it does contain one or two tidbits worth noting.

For example, in the section "Electronic commerce and information and communication technology (ICT) services" we read:

free flows of data are a critical component of the business model for service and manufacturing enterprises in the U.S. and the EU and key to their competitiveness.

But as we know, the European Parliament has come out against such "free flows", and wants to see European-style data protection for personal data when it leaves the EU.  So it will be interesting to see how that works out.

One aspect of TTIP that has not been discussed much yet concerns intellectual monopolies.  Here's what the USTR has to say on the subject:

We seek new opportunities to advance and defend the interests of U.S. creators, innovators, businesses, farmers, and workers with respect to strong protection and effective enforcement of intellectual property rights, including their ability to compete in foreign markets.

The question is: will the US try to use TAFTA/TTIP to bring in ACTA-like measures?  Since everything is being negotiated behind closed doors, we don't yet know, but I'm confident we'll soon see some leaks that gives us an insight into this crucial area.

Finally, there is the controversial area of investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS):

We recognize that trade agreements that are effectively enforced establish a set of high-standard rules and obligations that help keep markets open to U.S. exporters and investors and ensure a level playing field.  When we negotiate and implement a trade agreement, we expect our trading partners to stick by the rules and obligations they agreed to.  However, when our trading partners fall short of what they promised – whether to reduce tariffs, implement strong labor and environment provisions, or otherwise provide U.S. exporters fair and non-discriminatory treatment – we need a means to hold them accountable.  This is why we have this important objective to establish a fair and open dispute settlement mechanism.  Dispute settlement gives us a means to discuss our concerns in a timely way and to seek compensation if they are not addressed.  Dispute settlement with trading partners in T-TIP will give the American public the confidence that we not only negotiate strong, high-standard obligations, but that we also have the means to enforce them.

You've got to love the subtle suggestion that the European Union is some kind of large, fragmented banana republic where the rule of law is uncertain, and thus supranational tribunals of the kind employed by ISDS are indispensable.  Just can't trust that sneaky Euro-trash...

Meanwhile, we're starting to see some sectoral information about what various industry want from TTIP, and hidden away in the details there are some interesting angles.  For example, here is a "Proposal on US-EU Regulatory Cooperation" [.pdf] from The European Crop Protection Association (ECPA) and CropLife America (CLA).  As you might expect, most of that document falls outside the scope of this column, but there's one section that certainly touches on issues I've discussed before:

ECPA and CLA strongly support that the EU and US continue to promote (a) minimum standards of 10 years for protecting regulatory data, and (b) protection of CBI [Confidential Business Information] through Free Trade Agreements with other countries, where protection of regulatory data is sub-optimal. Protection of regulatory data from unauthorized use by competitors is essential for stimulating investment in research and development of agricultural crop protection products. This protection provides benefits to all stakeholders – from farmers to consumers – ultimately contributing to the economic development of industrialized and developing countries alike.

That "regulatory data" is essentially health and safety information.  This must be made available as open data, for the same reason that clinical data should be.  It allows it to be checked by independent researchers, and also allows it to be analysed and re-used in new ways.  Making it proprietary as the ECPA and CLA call for blocks those kind of uses.  As it becomes more widely recognised that data is a crucial resource for the future, we need a general principle that "regulatory data is always open data" to be enshrined not just in TTIP, but in all agreements.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XVIII

A lot has been happening on the TTIP front recently.  That's largely because of two factors.  First, that the real negotiations have begun, which is generating a lot of activity by all those involved.  And secondly, because resistance to some or even all of TTIP is growing, and that is manifesting itself in various ways.  For example, yesterday the important resolution on NSA surveillance passed by the European Parliament included the following key recommendation:

Parliament should withhold its consent to the final Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) deal with the US unless it fully respects EU fundamental rights, stresses the resolution, adding that data protection should be ruled out of the trade talks. This consent “could be endangered as long as blanket mass surveillance activities and the interception of communications in EU institutions and diplomatic representations are not fully stopped”, notes the text.

Interestingly, the leak of a document from 2012 [.pdf] reveals that getting consent for TTIP is going to be much harder than we thought.  The confidential legal opinion says that TTIP must be regarded as a "mixed agreement".  What that means in practical terms is that all 28 EU national parliaments must approve it - it's not just the European Parliament that gets to vote here.  That makes the barrier to getting TTIP through much higher.

There's more resistance in the form of a new site dedicated to TTIP put together by the Green/EFA Group of the European Parliament:

The European Greens do not believe that TTIP represents the kind of transatlantic relationship we need. As it currently stands, TTIP threatens our democracy and risks undermining our hard-won regulation and standards in a host of sectors.

We are against the current negotiation agenda that was set by business interests and is taking place in complete secrecy. Negotiations need to be in the full view of the public and their representatives, and the deal needs to promote and enhance social, environmental, health and consumer rights, not undermine them.

Contributions to this site will continue over the coming months. The Greens hope to provide a platform for concerned stakeholders to discuss the current state of the negotiations and what they could mean for citizens and democracy on both sides of the Atlantic.


Another new site is eu-secretdeals.info, which has an interesting emphasis on publishing leaked documents for both TTIP and the Canada-EU trade agreement (CETA):

By publishing negotiating texts, that reached us from anonymous sources, and by providing critical analysis of these texts, we hope to enable parliamentarians, academics, civil society organisations, media and the public to understand what the EU, the US and Canada are trying to do during the negotiations.

We are committed to a more transparent and democratic EU and international trade policy. And we invite all interested NGOs, academics and progressive political actors to contribute to this site with their insights and analysis of the leaked investment texts and investor-state dispute settlement generally.


As that suggests, the investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) element of TTIP (and CETA) remains problematic.  In fact, the main organisation that monitors this area - UNCTAD, the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development - published an important analysis [.pdf] of just how serious those problems were back in June 2013 (I've only just come across it, thanks to this excellent Swedish post rebutting the European Commission's attempts to justify ISDS that I wrote about my previous update.)

Here are the main issues with ISDS, as perceived by UNCTAD:

Legitimacy and transparency

Probably the main concern here, that ISDS will undermine measures in the public interest.

Arbitral decisions: problems of consistency and erroneous decisions

As UNCTAD points out, the decisions of the ISDS tribunals are often inconsistent, which makes them a nightmare to plan for and deal with - and hardly suitable for a treaty like TTIP.

Arbitrators: Concerns about party appointments and undue incentives

The members of ISDS tribunals may not be impartial, making their judgments even more problematic.

Cost- and time-intensity of arbitrations

ISDS cases typically cost around $8 million, which makes them punitively expensive. 

Those are the "old" problems, well-known for some time.  But new ways of abusing the ISDS system are cropping up all the time.  For example, an important new report from Corporate Europe Observatory (CEO) exposes how ISDS in existing treaties are being used in an attempt to extract huge sums from European nations worst-hit by the financial crisis:

For a long time, European countries were left unscathed by the rising global wave of investor-state disputes which had tended to target developing countries. In the wake of the global financial crisis, however, corporations and investment lawyers have turned their eyes to potential pickings in Europe. An investment regime, concocted in secretive European board rooms, and that gives corporations powerful rights to sue governments, has finally come home to roost.

Here's how it works:

Profiting from Crisis looks closely at how corporate investors have responded to the measures taken by Spain, Greece and Cyprus to protect their economies in the wake of the European debt crisis. In Greece, Poštová Bank from Slovakia bought Greek debt after the bond value had already been downgraded, and was then offered a very generous debt restructuring package, yet sought to extract an even better deal by suing Greece using the Bilateral Investment Treaty (BIT) between Slovakia and Greece. In Cyprus, a Greek-listed private equity-style investor, Marfin Investment Group, which was involved in a series of questionable lending practices, is seeking €823 million in compensation for their lost investments after Cyprus had to nationalise the Laiki Bank as part of an EU debt restructuring agreement. In Spain, 22 companies (at the time of writing), mainly private equity funds, have sued at international tribunals for cuts in subsidies for renewable energy. While the cuts in subsidies have been rightly criticised by environmentalists, only large foreign investors have the ability to sue, and it is egregious that if they win it will be the already suffering Spanish public who will have to pay to enrich private equity funds.

This is a great demonstration of how ISDS clauses can be misused.  These debt restructuring measures were brought in at the behest of the European Commission: the countries had no choice in the matter if they wanted EU support.  The austerity measures they formed part of have pushed large numbers of people into poverty, and yet the investors who have bought up debt cheaply are now trying to extract large sums from cash-strapped governments.  If the investors win, that money will come out of the public budget, and will inevitably mean further cuts in health services, education etc.

These ISDS cases have arisen purely from existing intra-EU treaties: imagine how things will be when US companies can join in.  And if you think only a few multi-national companies are involved, think again. As CEO says:

A total of 75,000 cross-registered companies with subsidiaries in both the EU and the US could launch investor-state attacks under the proposed transatlantic agreement. Europe’s experience of corporate speculators profiting from crisis should be a salutary warning that corporations’ rights need to be curtailed and peoples’ rights put first.

Of course, the European Commission's response to all these major issues is to say that we shouldn't worry, because it will all be sorted out in TTIP.  But as a previous Update showed, its attempts to do that in CETA don't inspire confidence.  That was based on some excellent work by the Seattle to Brussels Network; but I've recently discovered another, completely independent analysis of the same documents, this time from the International Institute for Sustainable Development [.pdf].  It's extremely thorough, and its conclusions are unequivocal:

In the end, and whatever the reason for the disconnect, we conclude that the actual draft legal texts in the public domain show that the European Commission’s assertions [about improving ISDS in CETA] are in most respects incorrect when compared to the draft legal text. The technical legal analysis is set out on each specific point below. In effect, the analysis indicates that the standards by which the European Commission itself seeks to demonstrate the success of the drafting actually show that the drafting has failed to meet its stated objectives, in fact, sometimes with the exact opposite result.

Here, though, I want to concentrate on one particular aspect that concerns "Most-Favoured Nation (MFN)", which could extremely serious ramifications if it is included in TTIP.  The situation for CETA is as follows:

Article X.8 of the November 2013 draft [of CETA] contains the MFN provision. In essence, it requires, for present analytical purposes, a European state to treat a foreign investor from Canada no less favourably than it treats an investor from any third state. The problem arises from the legal reality that such treatment has been defined in investment arbitrations as including the rights of other investors under investment treaties with the host state. So, if an EU member state that has a Canadian investor also has a treaty with an African, Latin American or any other state, the investor from Canada can import the provisions of that treaty if they are more favourable than the provisions of the CETA.

The impact of this is straightforward. The European Commission statement notes the need to “bring very significant clarifications” in order to give arbitrators “strict and detailed guidance when these provisions are invoked by an investor.” Now, we have already seen from the preceding analysis that this objective has not been met in the November 2013 draft text. But let us suppose, for the sake of understanding the current issue, that it had been met. The MFN provision would in any event undo this.

Arbitrators now routinely allow investors to essentially cherry-pick provisions from other investment treaties that are more favourable to it. To continue our example of a Canadian investor, let’s assume it makes a claim against an EU member state for expropriation under CETA. The exceptions and carve-outs would apply to it. However, if the same state has an old treaty with any other state, the investor can argue that the expropriation provision from that treaty, without the exceptions or carve-outs included in the CETA, should apply to its claim as a result of the CETA’s MFN provision. The benefits to the states of the more careful drafting are thus, quite simply, lost.


So, in the case of CETA, all of the European Commission's much-vaunted "improvements" to ISDS are completely nullified by the presence of this MFN clause.  We don't know if a similar MFN section will be in TTIP, but if it is, and it is as badly-worded as in CETA, it will have a similarly disastrous effect.  When the European Commission releases its ISDS consultation document (soon?) it must make absolutely clear what its position on MFN is.

However,  maybe it won't matter.  An article published todayin the German newspaper Die Zeit claims that the German government wants ISDS out of TTIP.  Obviously, that needs to be confirmed, but if it's true, it's hard to see how the European Commission will be able to push an agreement through if it contains ISDS.

Never a dull moment in the world of TTIP....

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+

TTIP Update XVII

In a previous update a couple of months ago, I discussed a low-key meeting that took place between  the European Commission and some of the biggest companies in the world (mostly from the US), which essentially revealed that the Commission was, after all, intending to bring back some of ACTA's worst ideas.  Things just became rather more worrying on this front as the result of the following announcement in the US:

This morning, President Obama nominated Robert Holleyman as deputy U.S. trade representative. If confirmed by the U.S. Senate, Holleyman will help lead the effort to pass the controversial Trans-Pacific Partnership trade deal.

Notably, Holleyman is a former lobbyist who led efforts to pass the Stop Online Piracy Act legislation, better known as SOPA, when he was leader of the Business Software Alliance. The SOPA debate (along with its sister legislation, PROTECT-IP, in the Senate) brought a spotlight on industry efforts to undermine Internet freedom through what many considered to be draconian intellectual property policy.


As that notes, he was formerly head of BSA; that means that he is no friend of open source.  Coupled with the European Commission's admission that it wants to bring in "Christmas list" of new demands in the area of intellectual monopolies, makes TTIP alll-the-more dangerous for both free software and online freedom.

Alongside that bad news, we've also had some good news in the shape of two significant leaks of relevant documents.  One concerns the Canada-EU trade agreement (CETA), which I discussed recently.  The German Pirate Party has obtained a copy of part of this agreement (.pdf), dating from December last year - quite recent, then.  Interestingly, even here there are sections that have still not been finalised. The leaked section concerns intellectual monopolies; a good early analysis of it has been made by Ante Wessels of FFII.  In particular, he compares its measures to those found in ACTA:

The damages in CETA do not contain the much criticized retail price damages, which were part of ACTA, the Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement, and are part of the EU – Singapore trade agreement proposal.

The injunctions do not contain “inaudita altera parte”, the much dreaded possibility to decide on injunctions without the infringer present.

So far so good. But, I do not see what was footnote 2 in ACTA, and is footnote 33 in the EU – Singapore agreement, the right to exclude patents from the scope of the civil enforcement section.

All the strong enforcement measures (damages, injunctions, provisional measures) will be available for software patent trolls.

The strong enforcement measures further create problems for access to knowledge and taking part in culture, for remix artists, and for inventors involved in sequential invention – like software developers.


Bad news, in other words.  And because agreements tend to build on one another - as I mentioned last year - it's very likely some of this language will re-appear in TTIP. 

The other leak is the European Commission's draft proposal on trade in services, investment and e-commerce for the TTIP negotiations [.pdf], obtained by the German newspaper Die Zeit.  Although it dates from July last year, it still offers some useful insight into the Commission's general thinking as regards TTIP.  That's also true of its latest official document, entitled "EU US Trade Agreement – The Facts" [.pdf]  This is very similar to the text that I discussed in October last year, headed "Incorrect claims about investor-state dispute settlement".  It takes the same form: statements allegedly made about TTIP, and their rebuttal.  For example:

TTIP will enable foreign firms to undermine EU laws. FALSE

An existing law cannot be undermined by a trade agreement. An existing ban on fracking or chlorine - washed chicken cannot be questioned, for example.


Although that's true, the European Commission omits to mention that  foreign firms will be able to undermine *future* laws by threatening to sue the EU or national governments if they are brought it.  This chilling effect is not merely theoretical: it has been happening for years in Canada, where NAFTA's ISDS chapter has allowed US companies to undermine proposed legislation in just this way.  If TTIP includes ISDS, it seems certain US companies will do the same here in Europe.  And remember that the great thing about such threats is that they can work even when it is not at all clear that the company would win in the ISDS tribunals: the mere possibility of such expensive actions is usually enough to "persuade" governments to back down.  That's the real danger here.

Moreover, from a true statement, the European Commission rather naughtily segues into an untrue one:

What the agreement does provide for – and this is in the EU's interest - is a ban on discrimination. That means that what applies to domestic firms must also apply to foreign firms.

What the Commission elides here is the fact that US companies will actually have *more* rights than EU companies in Europe, because EU companies are not able to sue there for any claimed "indirect expropriation of future profits", as US companies can using ISDS.  So introducing ISDS in TTIP will actually put EU companies at a disadvantage in their home markets.

TTIP will lead to privatisation in areas such as health care, water and education. FALSE

The TTIP Agreement has nothing to do with privatisation – only governments can decide that. No free trade agreement obliges the EU's Member States to liberalise or privatise the water industry or other public services, such as public health systems public transport or the education system.


Again, this misses the point - wilfully, perhaps.  The problem with TTIP is not that it will force nations to privatise services, but that once they are privatised, and provided by a US company, it will effectively be impossible to re-nationalise them.  That's because under ISDS that would amount to an "expropriation" of future profits, which would mean that the US companies concerned could sue the governments for those "lost" monies.  That would make re-nationalisation punitively expensive, and ensure that it rarely happened.

TTIP will restrict the rights of internet users. FALSE

Both the EU and the US have efficient regulations for protecting intellectual property rights, even though their respective regulations achieve their goals in different ways. The TTIP aims to simplify trade between the EU and the US without weakening these regulations. The TTIP will not be "ACTA throug h the back door" and it will not call into question the European Parliament's rejection of the trade agreement on combatting piracy of labels and products (ACTA).


As I noted above: the European Commission has already said to corporates that ACTA by the back door is precisely what it hopes to achieve here; the appointment of one of the main SOPA supporters as a key US negotiator guarantees that this will be high on the agenda.

The TTIP is undemocratic and elected politicians have no influence over it. FALSE

Both the EU's national parliaments as well as MEPs in the European P arliament have considerable influence on the TTIP negotiations. The European Commission is negotiating the trade agreement in the name of, and with a mandate from, the EU's Member States. The EU's negotiators meet weekly with representatives of the dem ocratically elected governments of the Member States in order to brief them 'live' before, during and after negotiating rounds and to take into consideration their positions. The European Parliament is also regularly informed of the state of the negotiati ons so that the positions and interests of the democratically elected parliamentarians can also be taken into consideration in the negotiations. Finally, it will be the EU Member States and the European Parliament which will have the last word on the TTIP and so it is obvious their interests will be taken into consideration.


This is nonsense.  Here's the reality:

USTR demands for hyper-secrecy in the Trans Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) continue to be a major block to continuing negotiations. The current issue under discussion is access to US proposals by EU member states — which are of course themselves sovereign countries. The member states are demanding access to the text of proposals that would constrain their domestic law making, as they ave had in all other EU trade agreements (e.g. the recent EU-Canada FTA). But Inside US Trade (2/28/2014) reports that USTR Froman has offered only that “he might be able to allow the European Commission to share the U.S. negotiating documents it receives if they were accessible only in a secure reading room.”

As that makes clear, even the "representatives of the democratically elected governments of the Member States" don't have access to all the relevant documents: they are currently being offered peeks in a "secure reading room" - how insulting is that? For MEPs, it's even worse:

There is no word yet on whether EU Members of Parliament will obtain access to consolidated TTIP text after each negotiation round, as was provided in at the end of the negotiation of the of the Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement (ACTA). Increased access to ACTA text for EU (but not US) legislative staff followed a March 2010 Resolution of the EU Parliament lambasting the Commission for its intense secrecy, including accusations of violations of the Lisbon Treaty governing EU affairs.

If MEPs can't even see the text, they are certainly not informed.  There's no way that they can exert "considerable influence" as the Commission claims if they don't know what's in the negotiating texts.  And that "last word" is literally that: a single, "yes" or "no" vote, where MEPs will be under tremendous pressure to accept the horrors - things like ISDS - for the sake of some much-needed growth.  Talking of which:

Why bother? The Transatlantic trade and Investment Partnership could have a similar effect to a package of economic stimulus measures. It could boost growth by 0.5% of GDP or some €120 bn, equivalent to €500 for every EU household because savings for companies also mean cheaper products, higher quality and more choice for consumers.

Yet again, the European Commission fails to note that the extra 0.5% GDP growth is compared to what would be obtained without TTIP *in 2027*, after 10 years of the agreement.  That means that even under the most favourable circumstances - something else it also fails to note - TTIP will increase GDP by just 0.05% each year on average.  It makes no sense to talk about the cumulative GDP effect: it might as well say that TTIP will produce 50% GDP growth - but without mentioning that would only be in 2117.  The only meaningful measure is the extra GDP growth that TTIP will produce *each year*, and that figure is 0.05%. 

Claiming that TTIP "could boost growth by 0.5% of GDP" without explaining that this is the  cumulative, not annual, figure is a serious misrepresentation of what its own projections suggest might happen in the best-case scenario - and certainly not a "fact" about the EU-US trade negotiations.

Follow me @glynmoody on Twitter or identi.ca, and +glynmoody on Google+